Wednesday, February 18, 2009

What Would Keynes Have Done?

The New York Times, November 30, 2008

ECONOMIC VIEW

What Would Keynes Have Done?

By N. GREGORY MANKIW

IF you were going to turn to only one economist to understand the problems

facing the economy, there is little doubt that the economist would be John

Maynard Keynes. Although Keynes died more than a half-century ago, his

diagnosis of recessions and depressions remains the foundation of modern

macroeconomics. His insights go a long way toward explaining the challenges

we now confront.

According to Keynes, the root cause of economic downturns is insufficient

aggregate demand. When the total demand for goods and services declines,

businesses throughout the economy see their sales fall off. Lower sales induce

firms to cut back production and to lay off workers. Rising unemployment and

declining profits further depress demand, leading to a feedback loop with a

very unhappy ending.

The situation reverses, Keynesian theory says, only when some event or policy

increases aggregate demand. The problem right now is that it is hard to see

where that demand might come from.

The economy’s output of goods and services is traditionally divided into four

components: consumption, investment, net exports and government

purchases. Any expansion in demand has to come from one of these four. But

in each case, strong forces are working to keep spending down.

CONSUMPTION The Conference Board reports that consumer confidence is

near its record low. It is easy to understand why consumers are so scared.

House values have declined, 401(k) balances have shrunk and unemployment

is up. For many people, the sense of economic uncertainty is greater than

they’ve ever experienced. When it comes to discretionary purchases, like a new

home, a car, or a washing machine, wait-and-see is the most rational course.

2

A bit more saving is not entirely unwelcome. Many economists have long

lamented the United States saving rate, which is low by international and

historical standards.

For the overall economy, however, a recession is not the best time for

households to start saving. Keynesian theory suggests a “paradox of thrift.” If

all households try to save more, a short-run result could be lower aggregate

demand and thus lower national income. Reduced incomes, in turn, could

prevent households from reaching their new saving goals.

INVESTMENT In normal times, a fall in consumption could be met by an

increase in investment, which includes spending by businesses on plant and

equipment and by households on new homes. But several factors are keeping

investment spending at bay.

The most obvious is the state of the housing market. Over the past three years,

residential investment has fallen 42 percent. With house prices continuing to

decline, increased building of new homes is not likely to be a source of robust

demand over the next few years.

Business investment has lately been stronger than residential investment, but

it is unlikely to pick up the slack in the near future. With the stock market

down, interest rates on corporate bonds up and the banking system teetering

on the edge, financing new business projects will not be easy.

NET EXPORTS Not long ago, it looked as if the rest of the world would save

the United States economy from a deep downturn. From March 2004 to

March 2008, the dollar fell 19 percent against an average of other major

currencies. By increasing the price of foreign goods in the United States and

reducing the price of American goods abroad, this depreciation discouraged

imports and bolstered exports. Over the last three years, real net exports have

increased by about $250 billion.

In the coming months, however, the situation may well go into reverse. As the

United States financial crisis has spread to the rest of the world, fast-moving

international capital has been looking for a safe haven. Ironically, that haven

3

is the United States. Since March, the dollar has appreciated 19 percent, a

move that will put a crimp in the export boom.

GOVERNMENT PURCHASES That leaves the government as the

demander of last resort. Calls for increased infrastructure spending fit well

with Keynesian theory. In principle, every dollar spent by the government

could cause national income to increase by more than a dollar if it leads to a

more vibrant economy and stimulates spending by consumers and companies.

By all reports, that is precisely the plan that the incoming Obama

administration has in mind.

The fly in the ointment — or perhaps it is more an elephant — is the long-term

fiscal picture. Increased government spending may be a good short-run fix,

but it would add to the budget deficit. The baby boomers are now starting to

retire and claim Social Security and Medicare benefits. Any increase in the

national debt will make fulfilling those unfunded promises harder in coming

years.

Keynesian economists often dismiss these long-run concerns when the

economy has short-run problems. “In the long run we are all dead,” Keynes

famously quipped.

The longer-term problem we now face, however, may be more serious than

any that Keynes ever envisioned. Passing a larger national debt to the next

generation may look attractive to those without children. (Keynes himself was

childless.) But the rest of us cannot feel much comfort knowing that, in the

long run, when we are dead, our children and grandchildren will be dealing

with our fiscal legacy.

So what is to be done? Many economists still hope the Federal Reserve will

save the day.

In normal times, the Fed can bolster aggregate demand by reducing interest

rates. Lower interest rates encourage households and companies to borrow

and spend. They also bolster equity values and, by encouraging international

4

capital to look elsewhere, reduce the value of the dollar in foreign-exchange

markets. Spending on consumption, investment and net exports all increase.

But these are not normal times. The Fed has already cut the federal funds rate

to 1 percent, close to its lower bound of zero. Some fear that our central bank

is almost out of ammunition.

Fortunately, the Fed has a few secret weapons. It can set a target for longerterm

interest rates. It can commit itself to keeping interest rates low for a

sustained period. Most important, it can try to manage expectations and

assure markets that it will do whatever it takes to avoid prolonged deflation.

The Fed’s decision last week to start buying mortgage debt shows its

willingness to act creatively.

It is hard to say how successful monetary and fiscal policy will be in avoiding a

deep downturn. But as events unfold, you can be sure that policymakers in the

Fed and Treasury will be looking at them through a Keynesian lens.

In 1936, Keynes wrote, “Practical men, who believe themselves to be quite

exempt from any intellectual influence, are usually the slave of some defunct

economist.” In 2008, no defunct economist is more prominent than Keynes

himself.

 

http://www.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/mankiw/files/Beyond%20the%20Noise.pdf

http://www.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/mankiw/files/Beyond%20the%20Noise.pdf